profit budget - meaning and definition. What is profit budget
Diclib.com
ChatGPT AI Dictionary
Enter a word or phrase in any language 👆
Language:

Translation and analysis of words by ChatGPT artificial intelligence

On this page you can get a detailed analysis of a word or phrase, produced by the best artificial intelligence technology to date:

  • how the word is used
  • frequency of use
  • it is used more often in oral or written speech
  • word translation options
  • usage examples (several phrases with translation)
  • etymology

What (who) is profit budget - definition

PROCESS TO DETERMINE THE HIGHEST PROFITS FOR A FIRM
Profit maximisation; Profit demand; Maximise profit; Profit function
  • Price setting by a monopolist
  • An example diagram of Profit Maximization: In the supply and demand graph, the output of <math>Q^*</math> is the intersection point of <math>\text{MR}</math> (Marginal Revenue) and <math>\text{MC}</math> (Marginal Cost), where <math>\text{MR}=\text{MC}</math>. The firm which produces at this output level is said to maximize profits.
If the output produced is less than the equilibrium quantity (<math>Q^*</math>), as shown in the red part, then <math>\text{MR}</math> is greater than <math>\text{MC}</math> (<math>\text{MR}>\text{MC}</math>), and the profit is not maximized. The firm has in its interest to raise its output level to maximize profits, because the revenue gained will be more than the cost to pay. 
However, if the output level is greater than <math>Q^*</math> (<math>\text{MR}<\text{MC}</math>), as shown in the blue part, the firm's overall profit will decrease because the additional unit produced will increase the overall cost. Here too the profit is not maximized and the firm has to lower its output level to maximize profits.

Profit (economics)         
  • In a regulated industry, the government examines firms' marginal cost structure and allows them to charge a price that is no greater than this marginal cost.  This does not necessarily ensure zero economic profit for the firm, but eliminates a [[monopoly profit]].
  • (monopoly) economic profit]].  An oligopoly usually has "economic profit" also, but usually faces an industry/market with more than just one firm (they must ''share'' available demand at the market price).
  • Only in the short run can a firm in a perfectly competitive market make an economic profit.
(IN THE ACCOUNTING SENSE OF THE EXCESS OF REVENUE OVER COST) SUM OF TWO COMPONENTS: NORMAL PROFIT AND ECONOMIC PROFIT
Economic Profit; Economic profits; Normal profit; Economic profit; Profitability; Profitable; Supernormal profits; Subnormal profit; Normal Profit; Excessive profits; Excess profit; Excessive profit; Economic profitability; Normal economic profit; Elements of economic profit; Monopolistic profit; Normal profits; Personal gain; Abnormal profits
A profit is the difference between the revenue that an economic entity has received from its outputs and the opportunity costs of its inputs.
profitable         
  • In a regulated industry, the government examines firms' marginal cost structure and allows them to charge a price that is no greater than this marginal cost.  This does not necessarily ensure zero economic profit for the firm, but eliminates a [[monopoly profit]].
  • (monopoly) economic profit]].  An oligopoly usually has "economic profit" also, but usually faces an industry/market with more than just one firm (they must ''share'' available demand at the market price).
  • Only in the short run can a firm in a perfectly competitive market make an economic profit.
(IN THE ACCOUNTING SENSE OF THE EXCESS OF REVENUE OVER COST) SUM OF TWO COMPONENTS: NORMAL PROFIT AND ECONOMIC PROFIT
Economic Profit; Economic profits; Normal profit; Economic profit; Profitability; Profitable; Supernormal profits; Subnormal profit; Normal Profit; Excessive profits; Excess profit; Excessive profit; Economic profitability; Normal economic profit; Elements of economic profit; Monopolistic profit; Normal profits; Personal gain; Abnormal profits
1.
A profitable organization or practice makes a profit.
Drug manufacturing is the most profitable business in America...
It was profitable for them to produce large amounts of food.
ADJ: oft it v-link ADJ to-inf
profitably
The 28 French stores are trading profitably.
ADV: ADV with v
profitability
Changes were made in operating methods in an effort to increase profitability.
N-UNCOUNT
2.
Something that is profitable results in some benefit for you.
...collaboration which leads to a profitable exchange of personnel and ideas.
ADJ: usu ADJ n
profitably
In fact he could scarcely have spent his time more profitably.
ADV: ADV with v
Profitable         
  • In a regulated industry, the government examines firms' marginal cost structure and allows them to charge a price that is no greater than this marginal cost.  This does not necessarily ensure zero economic profit for the firm, but eliminates a [[monopoly profit]].
  • (monopoly) economic profit]].  An oligopoly usually has "economic profit" also, but usually faces an industry/market with more than just one firm (they must ''share'' available demand at the market price).
  • Only in the short run can a firm in a perfectly competitive market make an economic profit.
(IN THE ACCOUNTING SENSE OF THE EXCESS OF REVENUE OVER COST) SUM OF TWO COMPONENTS: NORMAL PROFIT AND ECONOMIC PROFIT
Economic Profit; Economic profits; Normal profit; Economic profit; Profitability; Profitable; Supernormal profits; Subnormal profit; Normal Profit; Excessive profits; Excess profit; Excessive profit; Economic profitability; Normal economic profit; Elements of economic profit; Monopolistic profit; Normal profits; Personal gain; Abnormal profits
·adj Yielding or bringing profit or gain; gainful; lucrative; useful; helpful; advantageous; beneficial; as, a profitable trade; profitable business; a profitable study or profession.

Wikipedia

Profit maximization

In economics, profit maximization is the short run or long run process by which a firm may determine the price, input and output levels that will lead to the highest possible total profit (or just profit in short). In neoclassical economics, which is currently the mainstream approach to microeconomics, the firm is assumed to be a "rational agent" (whether operating in a perfectly competitive market or otherwise) which wants to maximize its total profit, which is the difference between its total revenue and its total cost.

Measuring the total cost and total revenue is often impractical, as the firms do not have the necessary reliable information to determine costs at all levels of production. Instead, they take a more practical approach by examining how small changes in production influence revenues and costs. When a firm produces an extra unit of product, the additional revenue gained from selling it is called the marginal revenue ( MR {\displaystyle {\text{MR}}} ), and the additional cost to produce that unit is called the marginal cost ( MC {\displaystyle {\text{MC}}} ). When the level of output is such that the marginal revenue is equal to the marginal cost ( MR = MC {\displaystyle {\text{MR}}={\text{MC}}} ), then the firm's total profit is said to be maximized. If the marginal revenue is greater than the marginal cost ( MR > MC {\displaystyle {\text{MR}}>{\text{MC}}} ), then its total profit is not maximized, because the firm can produce additional units to earn additional profit. In other words, in this case, it is in the "rational" interest of the firm to increase its output level until its total profit is maximized. On the other hand, if the marginal revenue is less than the marginal cost ( MR < MC {\displaystyle {\text{MR}}<{\text{MC}}} ), then too its total profit is not maximized, because producing one unit less will reduce total cost more than total revenue gained, thus giving the firm more total profit. In this case, a "rational" firm has an incentive to reduce its output level until its total profit is maximized.

There are several perspectives one can take on profit maximization. First, since profit equals revenue minus cost, one can plot graphically each of the variables revenue and cost as functions of the level of output and find the output level that maximizes the difference (or this can be done with a table of values instead of a graph). Second, if specific functional forms are known for revenue and cost in terms of output, one can use calculus to maximize profit with respect to the output level. Third, since the first order condition for the optimization equates marginal revenue and marginal cost, if marginal revenue ( MR {\displaystyle {\text{MR}}} ) and marginal cost ( MC {\displaystyle {\text{MC}}} ) functions in terms of output are directly available one can equate these, using either equations or a graph. Fourth, rather than a function giving the cost of producing each potential output level, the firm may have input cost functions giving the cost of acquiring any amount of each input, along with a production function showing how much output results from using any combination of input quantities. In this case one can use calculus to maximize profit with respect to input usage levels, subject to the input cost functions and the production function. The first order condition for each input equates the marginal revenue product of the input (the increment to revenue from selling the product caused by an increment to the amount of the input used) to the marginal cost of the input.

For a firm in a perfectly competitive market for its output, the revenue function will simply equal the market price times the quantity produced and sold, whereas for a monopolist, which chooses its level of output simultaneously with its selling price. In the case of monopoly, the company will produce more products because it can still make normal profits. To get the most profit, you need to set higher prices and lower quantities than the competitive market. However, the revenue function takes into account the fact that higher levels of output require a lower price in order to be sold. An analogous feature holds for the input markets: in a perfectly competitive input market the firm's cost of the input is simply the amount purchased for use in production times the market-determined unit input cost, whereas a monopsonist’s input price per unit is higher for higher amounts of the input purchased.

The principal difference between short run and long run profit maximization is that in the long run the quantities of all inputs, including physical capital, are choice variables, while in the short run the amount of capital is predetermined by past investment decisions. In either case, there are inputs of labor and raw materials.